Mark your calendars: This Monday, May 1, Tim B. Lee of Full Stack Economics will join our Zoom for paid subscribers at 8 PM New York Time to talk about his new Substack, Understanding AI. Then on May 8 Bryan Caplan will join us to talk about his latest collection of essays, Voters as Mad Scientists.
This business — “fractional reserve banking,” it is often called is inherently risky and fragile. Everyone knows this, and there are standard methods to mitigate the risks. Banks have capital requirements (they are partly funded with equity, not deposits, so if the assets lose value the depositors still get their money back). They have liquidity (some of their assets are short term and safe, so if depositors want money back there’s some money to give them). There is safety-and-soundness regulation and supervision (the government tries to prevent banks from making loans that will lose money). There is deposit insurance (the government promises that depositors will get their money back, making bank accounts safer and runs less likely). Still there is some unavoidable residue of fragility: The mismatch between the banks’ safe short term liabilities and their risky long term assets creates risk, and somebody — if not depositors then the government — has to bear that risk.
He points out that periodically some economists (I’m looking at you, John Cochrane) say that banks should be forced to hold only short-term, low-risk assets against deposits. This is called “narrow banking.” Levine writes,
Meanwhile, risky loans would come from people who intend to make risky loans: You could have, say, a loan fund that raises money from investors, locks up their money for 10 years, uses the money to make 10-year loans, and then pays back the investors whatever the fund gets back on the loans.[4] If the fund makes bad loans, the investors lose money; they bear the risk knowingly and directly, unlike bank depositors who sort of don’t know where their money is going.
But this is not where I think the industry would end up. Somebody, somewhere would notice that they could make a profit by engaging in liquidity transformation. That is, liabilities walk in the door that are long-term and risky, and liabilities walk out the door that are short-term and riskless, and nobody is the wiser.
The point of his article is that with the Fed’s “reverse repo” program, money market funds can act like narrow banks and have fun doing it.
A money market fund that just parks its money at the Fed has essentially no risk: All of its assets are short-term (they are parked overnight) and safe (its debtor is the Fed), so your money is safer there than it is at a bank. It has few expenses: It doesn’t need a branch network or a lot of lending officers to take in money online and park it at the Fed, so it can pass on most of the interest that the Fed pays it directly to its customers. And the Fed does pay it a lot of interest — reverse repos pay something like 4.8% — so it can end up paying depositors more interest for taking less risk than a bank can.
Ironically, the Fed makes it easier for money market funds to be narrow banks than it is for actual banks to be narrow banks. Go figure.
I am more optimistic than Levine about the viability of liability transformation. I have a piece scheduled to come out this summer that will explain how it could be managed. But I have serious doubts about the existing institutional structure, anchored by the FDIC, in terms of its ability to manage a regime with banks undertaking liability transformation.
Levine- sigh. This is academic speak where you get to define things at the outset and then move on. Arnold, your point about the transformation is spot on, but it goes deeper than that. If you define something as low risk or risk free in a regulatory environment you cause it to become risky, because you are artificially creating demand for a product and so supply must follow. Government debt is not risk free despite what academics might say, and finance does not work on the principle of getting your principle back. Always ignored in such proposals is that money is only good as a medium of exchange, getting $100 nominal dollars back means nothing as far as risk is concerned as the value of the money has to constantly be able to satisfy the chain of obligations (not debt). To take the money market fund example does Levine mention that the Fed is losing money on those interest payments? That they can print to pay for those payments is a major mistake in judgement. With QE they purchase (or really create an asset swap) securities which means they can either sell them back to the market and neutralize part or all of their purchase in the future, or they can collect coupon payments and retire those dollars. With interest payments they have no asset to swap back into the market if they want to reverse the effects of their monetary policy. The opposite action would be to charge interest on reserves, but they cannot force such reserves in the first place. Even without the market transforming risk from self interest you get a transformation of risk- from bank runs to currency runs. In short the imagined 'stable' system would be vulnerable to the greatest destabilization- hyper inflation and the death of the currency.
Levin seems to confound two different kind of risks that bank might undertake a) term transformation risks: depositors want their money that has been lent out at long term and b) interest rate mismatch risk: the rate needed to hold deposits or replace them with other short term liabilities rises but investments have been mad ein long term-_fixed rate_ loans. This was the S&L problem of the '70's. Banks and regulatora apparent ly for got about this kid of risk and how to avoid it