Discussion about this post

User's avatar
Helen Dale's avatar

I'm hoping Lorenzo hasn't gone to bed (he may have - it's quite late on Saturday evening in Australia). I'm sure he'll have a response :)

For my part, "not just in the US" applies to this observation: "my intuition is that the main problem in the U.S. economy is that too many highly educated people work for government and for non-profits, where they mostly make trouble for the productive sector. There are workers who could be useful and decently paid in infrastructure, energy production, and housing construction—if the moochers would get out of the way."

In the UK & Australia, NGOs and many charities have become actively destructive to the wider economy, and not just through obvious things like encouraging their members to block roads during protests.

Expand full comment
Lorenzo Warby's avatar

The criticism of not crediting Nobel Memorial Herbert Simon with satisficing is absolutely fair and will be corrected in the published version.

Satisficing does not seem, however, to have been taken up all that much. Maximisation is much more tractable mathematically. Also, satisficing does have a bit of a “how long is a piece of string?” problem. Hence the point about salience. Not sure how more mathematically tractable it makes the concept, but it does at least point to what to consider.

I have no particular problem with the land/labour/capital division in factors of production. You can, for instance, usefully analyse the politics of trade post steamships and railways on the basis of which was scarce or plentiful in a particular country: scarce factors of production favoured protection, plentiful factors favoured free trade. Two out of three determined whether free trade or protectionist pressures won.

The skilled/unskilled labour division strikes me as better analysed as there being a spectrum in the mixing of labour and capital. That is, they are different factors of production, but often not separate.

The bigger problem is with lumping in financing with the “rest” of capital. Ownership follows who covers the risks: which is about financial resources much more than physical plant and equipment. Calling it all “capital” muddies thinking and encourages “wind-up toy” analyses of economic growth.

Using migration to raise returns to capital, but depress returns to labour, has problems, apart from increasing inequality and social division. If you want to encourage technological progress, you want higher wages not lower: more productive workers that generate a bigger return in adding capital.

As for gardening, etc. services in Australia, they are provided by bog-standard self-employed providers, often on a franchise system, not notably dominated by migrants. One is quite likely to have native-born folk providing gardening services to migrants. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Jim's_Mowing

Also agree that treating migrants as interchangeable widgets is pretty silly.

The multiplying categories of capital, the produced means of production, is an issue. Part of the problem is that Economics tends to be a little exchange/transaction obsessed and less concerned with connection. Coercion, exchange, connection and structured sharing (“pooling”) are the base social interactions. Gifts, for instance, are investments in connection. Calling connection ‘social capital’ helps economists consider it, though not as much as they should. (The anthropologists’ term of ‘relational wealth’ is perhaps not much of an improvement.)

As for too many folk in non-productive (or even anti-productive) jobs absolutely. Patterns of such interior colonisation of our societies will be a continuing theme in future essays in the series.

Expand full comment
11 more comments...

No posts